CHAPTER Four

elasticity

CHAPTER OVERVIEW

This is the second chapter in Part Two, “Price, Quantity, and Efficiency.”  Both the elasticity coefficient and the total revenue test for measuring price elasticity of demand are presented in the chapter.  The text attempts to sharpen students’ ability to estimate price elasticity by discussing its major determinants.  The chapter reviews a number of applications and presents empirical estimates for a variety of products.  Income elasticities of supply is also addressed.

The law of demand is explained in terms of (1) the income and substitution effects and (2) diminishing marginal utility.  The latter approach leads into a detailed discussion of the theory of consumer choice.  The numerical illustrations of the utility‑maximizing rule should be viewed as a pedagogical technique, rather than an attempt to portray the actual choice‑making process of consumers.  When this illustration is explained by “order of purchase,” the brief algebraic summary of consumer equilibrium should pose no great difficulties for most students. The discussion of the diamond-water paradox helps students look beyond what may be their first conclusions about the importance and value of products.

The opportunity cost of time may be considered as a component of product price.  This chapter concludes with a simplified integration of time into the theory of consumer behavior.

 

INSTRUCTIONAL OBJECTIVES

     1.    Define price elasticity of demand and compute the coefficient of elasticity given appropriate data on prices and quantities.

     2.    Explain the meaning of elastic, inelastic, and unitary price elasticity of demand.

     3.    Recognize graphs of perfectly elastic and perfectly inelastic demand.

     4.    Use the total‑revenue test to determine whether elasticity of demand is elastic, inelastic, or unitary.

     5.    List four major determinants of price elasticity of demand.

     6.    Explain how a change in each of the determinants of price elasticity would affect the elasticity coefficient.

     7.    Define price elasticity of supply and explain how the producer’s ability to shift resources to alternative uses and time affect price elasticity of supply.

     8.    Define income elasticity and its relationship to normal and inferior goods.

     9.    Apply the various types of elasticity to contemporary issues such as taxation and drug policy.

 10.    Define and identify the terms and concepts listed at end of the chapter.

RATIONAL BEHAVIOR
MARGINAL UTILITY
 DIMINISHING MARGINAL UTILITY
TOTAL UTILITY
BUDGET CONSTRAINT
UTILITY MAXIMIZING FORMULA
TOTAL REVENUE TEST
ELASTICITY OF SUPPLY
SHORT RUN
ELASTICITY
LONG RUN
ELASTIC DEMAND
INELASTIC DEMAND
UNIT ELASTICITY
PERFECT ELASTIC
PERFECT INELASTIC
TOTAL REVENUE

 


LECTURE NOTES

I.  Learning objectives

A.   Understand total utility, marginal utility, and the law of diminishing marginal utility

B.   How rational consumers compare marginal utility-to-price ratios for products in purchasing combinations of products that maximize their utility

C.   How a demand curve can be derived by observing the outcomes of price changes in the utility-maximization mode

D.   How the utility-maximization model helps highlight the income and substitution effects of a price change

E.   About price elasticity of demand and how it can be applied.

F.   The usefulness of the total revenue test for price elasticity of demand.

G.   About price elasticity of supply and how it can be applied.

H.   About cross elasticity of demand and income elasticity of demand.

I.   About consumer surplus, producer surplus, and efficiency (deadweight) loss.

 

II.        Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility

A.  Although consumer wants in general are insatiable, wants for specific commodities can be fulfilled.  The more of a specific product that consumers obtain, the less they will desire more units of that product.  This can be illustrated with almost any item.  The text uses the automobile example, but houses, clothing, and even food items work just as well.

B.   Utility is a subjective notion in economics, referring to the amount of satisfaction a person gets from consumption of a certain item.

C.   Marginal utility refers to the extra utility a consumer gets from one additional unit of a specific product.  In a short period of time, the marginal utility derived from successive units of a given product will decline.  This is known as diminishing marginal utility.

D.  Figure 19.1 and the accompanying table illustrate the relationship between total and marginal utility.

      1.   Total utility increases as each additional burger is purchased through the first fourteen, but utility rises at a diminishing rate since each burger adds less and less to the consumer’s satisfaction.

      2.   Marginal utility becomes zero at some point, and then even negative--at the fifteenth unit and beyond.  If more than fourteen tacos were purchased, total utility would begin to fall.  This illustrates the law of diminishing marginal utility.

Consider This … Vending Machines and Marginal Utility
  •  Newspaper vending machines normally allow one to take multiple papers; publishers allow this because they believe that people rarely take more than one paper because the marginal utility of the second paper is often zero, and it has little “shelf life.”
  •  Soft drink vending machines distribute one can or bottle at a time.  Even if the marginal utility of the second unit of soda is low in the short run, the long shelf life would allow people to keep sodas for later consumption.

III.  Theory of consumer behavior uses the law of diminishing marginal utility to explain how consumers allocate their income.

A.  Consumer choice and the budget constraint:

1.   Consumers are assumed to be rational, i.e. they are trying to get the most value for their money.

2.   Consumers have clear‑cut preferences for various goods and services and can judge the utility they receive from successive units of various purchases.

3.   Consumers’ incomes are limited because their individual resources are limited.  Thus, consumers face a budget constraint. (As we saw with the individual budget line in Chapter 1)

4.   Goods and services have prices and are scarce relative to the demand for them.  Consumers must choose among alternative goods with their limited money incomes.

B.   Utility maximizing rule explains how consumers decide to allocate their money incomes so that the last dollar spent on each product purchased yields the same amount of extra (marginal) utility.

1.   A consumer is in equilibrium when utility is “balanced (per dollar) at the margin.” When this is true, there is no incentive to alter the expenditure pattern unless tastes, income, or prices change.

2.   Table 19.1 provides a numerical example of this for an individual named Holly with $10 to spend.  Follow the reasoning process to see why 2 units of A and 4 of B will maximize Holly’s utility, given the $10 spending limit.

3.   It is marginal utility per dollar spent that is equalized; that is, consumers compare the extra utility from each product with its cost.

4.   As long as one good provides more utility per dollar than another, the consumer will buy more of the first good; as more of the first product is bought, its marginal utility diminishes until the amount of utility per dollar just equals that of the other product.

5.   Table 19.2 summarizes the step-by-step decision‑making process the rational consumer will pursue to reach the utility‑maximizing combination of goods and services attainable.

6.   The algebraic statement of this utility-maximizing state is that the consumer will allocate income in such a way that:

      MU of product A/price of A = MU of product B/price of B = etc.

IV.       Utility Maximization and the Demand Curve

A.  Determinants of an individual’s demand curve are tastes, income, and prices of other goods.

B.   Deriving the demand curve can be illustrated using item B in Table 19.1 and considering alternative prices at which B might be sold.  At lower prices, using the utility‑maximizing rule, we see that more will be purchased as the price falls.

C.   The utility‑maximizing rule helps to explain the substitution effect and the income effect.

1.   When the price of an item declines, the consumer will no longer be in equilibrium until more of the item is purchased and the marginal utility of the item declines to match the decline in price.  More of this item is purchased rather than another relatively more expensive substitute.

2.   The income effect is shown by the fact that a decline in price expands the consumer’s real income and the consumer must purchase more of this and other products until equilibrium is once again attained for the new level of real income.

V.          Introduction to Elasticity

A.  Elasticity of demand measures how much the quantity demanded changes with a given change in price of the item, change in consumers income, or change in price of related product.

B.   Price elasticity is a concept that also relates to supply.

C.   The chapter explores both elasticity of supply and demand and applications of the concept.

VI.        Price Elasticity of Demand

A.  Law of demand tells us that consumers will respond to a price decrease by buying more of a product (other things remaining constant), but it does not tell us how much more.

B.   Elasticity of demand measures how much the quantity demanded changes with a given change in price of the item, change in consumers’ income, or change in price of related product.

C The degree of responsiveness or sensitivity of consumers to a change in price is measured by the concept of price elasticity of demand.

1.   If consumers are relatively responsive to price changes, demand is said to be elastic.

2.   If consumers are relatively unresponsive to price changes, demand is said to be inelastic.

3.   Note that with both elastic and inelastic demand, consumers behave according to the law of demand; that is, they are responsive to price changes. The terms elastic or inelastic describe the degree of responsiveness.  A precise definition of what we mean by “responsive” or “unresponsive” follows.

CONSIDER THIS … A Bit of a Stretch

  • The Ace bandage stretches a lot when force is applied (elastic); the rubber tie-down (not to be confused with a rubber band) moves stretches little when force is applied (inelastic).

D.   Price elasticity coefficient and formula:

      Quantitative measure of elasticity, Ed = percentage change in quantity/ percentage change in price.

1.   Using two price-quantity combinations of a demand schedule, calculate the percentage change in quantity by dividing the absolute change in quantity by one of the two original quantities. Then calculate the percentage change in price by dividing the absolute change in price by one of the two original prices.

2.   Estimate the elasticity of this region of the demand schedule by comparing the percentage change in quantity and the percentage change in price.  Do not use the ratio formula at this time.  Emphasize that it is the two percentage changes that are being compared when determining elasticity.

3.   Show that if the other original quantity and price were used as the denominator that the percentage changes would be different.  Explain that a way to deal with this problem is to use the average of the two quantities and the average of the two prices.

4.   Using averages – the midpoint formula

a.   Using traditional calculations, the measured elasticity over a given range of prices is sensitive to whether one starts at the higher price and goes down, or the lower price and goes up.  The midpoint formula calculates the average elasticity over a range of prices to alleviate that problem

b.   The midpoint formula for elasticity is:

            Ed = [(change in Q)/(sum of Q’s/2)] divided by [(change in P)/(sum of P’s/2

c.   Have the students calculate each of the percentage changes separately to determine whether the demand is elastic or inelastic.  After the students have determined the type of elasticity, then have them insert the percentage changes into the formula.  

The midpoint formula is ridiculously complicated and useless.  Use the "Good Enough Formula":

            Ed = [(Q2 - Q1/Q1) divided by (P2 - P1/P1)]

5.   Emphasis: The percentages changes are compared, not the absolute changes.

a.   Absolute changes depend on choice of units.  For example, a change in the price of a $10,000 car by $1 and is very different than a change in the price a of $1 can of beer by $1.  The auto’s price is rising by a fraction of a percent while the beer rice is rising 100 percent.

b.   Percentages also make it possible to compare elasticities of demand for different products. 

6.   Because of the inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded, the actual elasticity of demand will be a negative number.  However, we ignore the minus sign and use absolute value of both percentage changes.

7.   If the coefficient of elasticity of demand is a number greater than one, we say demand is elastic; if the coefficient is less than one, we say demand is inelastic. In other words, the quantity demanded is “relatively responsive” when Ed is greater than 1 and “relatively unresponsive” when Ed is less than 1.  A special case is if the coefficient equals one; this is called unit elasticity.

8.   Note: Inelastic demand does not mean that consumers are completely unresponsive.  This extreme situation called perfectly inelastic demand would be very rare, and the demand curve would be vertical.

9.   Likewise, elastic demand does not mean consumers are completely responsive to a price change.  This extreme situation, in which a small price reduction would cause buyers to increase their purchases from zero to all that it is possible to obtain, is perfectly elastic demand, and the demand curve would be horizontal.

 

D.  Graphical analysis

1.   Illustrate graphically perfectly elastic, relatively elastic, unitary elastic, relative inelastic, and perfectly inelastic. (Figures 18.1 and 18.2)

2.   Using Figure 18.2, explain that elasticity varies over range of prices.

a.   Demand is more elastic in upper left portion of curve (because price is higher, quantity smaller).

b.   Demand is more inelastic in lower right portion of curve (because price is lower, quantity larger).

3.   It is impossible to judge elasticity of a single demand curve by its flatness or steepness, since demand elasticity can measure both elastic and inelastic at different points on the same demand curve.

E.   Total-revenue test is the easiest way to judge whether demand is elastic or inelastic.  This test can be used in place of elasticity formula, unless there is a need to determine the elasticity coefficient.

1.   Elastic demand and the total-revenue test: Demand is elastic if a decrease in price results in a rise in total revenue, or if an increase in price results in a decline in total revenue.  (Price and revenue move in opposite directions).

2.   Inelastic demand and the total-revenue test: Demand is inelastic if a decrease in price results in a fall in total revenue, or an increase in price results in a rise in total revenue.  (Price and revenue move in same direction).

3.   Unit elasticity and the total-revenue test: Demand has unit elasticity if total revenue does not change when the price changes.

4.   The graphical representation of the relationship between total revenue and price elasticity:


 

.

F.   There are several determinants of the price elasticity of demand.

1.   Substitutes for the product: Generally, the more substitutes, the more elastic the demand.

2.   The proportion of price relative to income: Generally, the larger the expenditure relative to one’s budget, the more elastic the demand, because buyers notice the change in price more.

3.   Whether the product is a luxury or a necessity: Generally, the less necessary the item, the more elastic the demand.

4.   The amount of time involved: Generally, the longer the time period involved, the more elastic the demand becomes.

G.  Table 18.3 presents some real‑world price elasticities.  Use the determinants discussed to see if the actual elasticities are equivalent to what one would predict.  

H.  There are many practical applications of the price elasticity of demand.

1.   Inelastic demand for agricultural products helps to explain why bumper crops depress the prices and total revenues for farmers.

2.   Governments look at elasticity of demand when levying excise taxes.  Excise taxes on products with inelastic demand will raise the most revenue and have the least impact on quantity demanded for those products.

3.   Demand for cocaine is highly inelastic and presents problems for law enforcement.  Stricter enforcement reduces supply, raises prices and revenues for sellers, and provides more incentives for sellers to remain in business.  Crime may also increase as buyers have to find more money to buy their drugs. 

a.   Opponents of legalization think that occasional users or “dabblers” have a more elastic demand and would increase their use at lower, legal prices.

b.   Removal of the legal prohibitions might make drug use more socially acceptable and shift demand to the right.

VII.       Price Elasticity of Supply

A.  The concept of price elasticity also applies to supply.  The elasticity formula is the same as that for demand, but we must substitute the word “supplied” for the word “demanded” everywhere in the formula.

      Es = percentage change in quantity supplied / percentage change in price

      As with price elasticity of demand, the midpoints formula is more accurate, but the "Close Enough Formula" works as well.

B.   The ease of shifting resources between alternative uses is very important in price elasticity of supply because it will determine how much flexibility a producer has to adjust his/her output to a change in the price. The degree of flexibility, and therefore the time period, will be different in different industries. (Figure 18.4)

1.   The market period is so short that elasticity of supply is inelastic; it could be almost perfectly inelastic or vertical.  In this situation, it is virtually impossible for producers to adjust their resources and change the quantity supplied.  (Think of adjustments on a farm once the crop has been planted.)

2.   The short‑run supply elasticity is more elastic than the market period and will depend on the ability of producers to respond to price change.  Industrial producers are able to make some output changes by having workers work overtime or by bringing on an extra shift.

3.   The long‑run supply elasticity is the most elastic, because more adjustments can be made over time and quantity can be changed more relative to a small change in price, as in Figure 18.4c.  The producer has time to build a new plant.

C.   Applications of the price elasticity of supply.

1.   Antiques and other non-reproducible commodities are inelastic in supply, sometimes the supply is perfectly inelastic.  This makes their prices highly susceptible to fluctuations in demand

2.   Gold prices are volatile because the supply of gold is highly inelastic, and unstable demand resulting from speculation causes prices to fluctuate significantly.

VIII.        Consumer and Producer Surplus

A.  Consumer Surplus

1.   Definition – the difference between the maximum price a consumer is (or consumers are)                willing to pay for a product and the actual price.

2.   The surplus, measurable in dollar terms, reflects the extra utility gained from paying a  lower price than what is required to obtain the good.

3.   Consumer surplus can be measured by calculating the difference between the maximum willingness to pay and the actual price for each consumer, and then summing those   differences.

4.   Consumer surplus is measured and represented graphically by the area under the demand curve and above the equilibrium price.  (Figure 18.5)

5.   Consumer surplus and price are inversely related – all else equal, a higher price reduces consumer surplus.

B.   Producer Surplus

      1.   Definition – the difference between the actual price a producer receives (or producers receive) and the minimum acceptable price.

      2.   Producer surplus can be measured by calculating the difference between the minimum acceptable price and the actual price for each unit sold, and then summing those differences.

      3.   Producer surplus is measured and represented graphically by the area above the supply curve and below the equilibrium price.  (Figure 18.6)

      4.   Producer surplus and price are directly related – all else equal, a higher price increases  producer surplus.

IX.       Efficiency Revisited

        A.  Efficiency is attained at equilibrium, where the combined consumer and producer surplus is maximized.  (Figure 18.7)

                 1.   Consumers receive utility up to their maximum willingness to pay, but only have to pay the equilibrium price. 

                 2.   Producers receive the equilibrium price for each unit, but it only costs the minimum  acceptable price to produce.

                  3.   Allocative efficiency occurs at quantity levels where three conditions exist:

                        a.   MB = MC

                        b.   Maximum willingness to pay = minimum acceptable price.

                        c.   Combined consumer and producer surplus is at a maximum.

B.   Efficiency (Deadweight) Losses

1.   Underproduction reduces both consumer and producer surplus, and efficiency is lost because both buyers and sellers would be willing to exchange a higher quantity.

2.   Overproduction causes inefficiency because past the equilibrium quantity, it costs society more to produce the good than it is worth to the consumer in terms of willingness to pay.

 

 

CONSUMER CHOICE and ELASTICITY

MARGINAL UTILITY

  • LAW OF DIMINISHING MARGINAL UTILITY
  • IRRATIONAL GOODS
  • MU of product A/price of A = MU of product B/price of B = etc.

ELASTICITY

  • DETERMINANTS OF ELASTICITY
    • TIME
    • SUBSTITUTES
    • NECESSITY
    • INCOME
  • TOTAL REVENUE TEST
    • P = TR
      • E<1, INELASTIC
    • P = TR
      • E>1, ELASTIC
  • "Close Enough Formula":

  • E =

    (Q2 - Q1/Q1)

    (P2 - P1/P1)

  • DEMAND CURVES
    • MORE ELASTIC AT HIGH PRICES
    • MORE INELASTIC AT LOW PRICES
    • UNIT ELASTIC AT EQUILIBRIUM