I.
Introduction
A.
One major function of the government is to stabilize the economy
(prevent unemployment or inflation).
B.
Stabilization can be achieved in part by manipulating the
public budget—government spending and tax collections—to increase
output and employment or to reduce inflation.
C.
This chapter will examine a number of topics.
1.
It explores the tools of government fiscal stabilization
policy using AD-AS model.
2.
Both discretionary and automatic fiscal adjustments are
examined.
3.
The problems, criticisms, and complications of fiscal policy
are addressed.
4.
The public debt and its effects on the economy, both real and
imagined, are explored.
5.
Investigation of the long-run fiscal imbalances in the Social
Security system conclude the chapter.
II.
Fiscal Policy and the AD/AS Model
A.
Discretionary fiscal policy refers to the deliberate manipulation of
taxes and government spending by Congress to alter real domestic
output and employment, control inflation, and stimulate economic
growth. “Discretionary”
means the changes are at the option of the Federal government.
B. Fiscal
policy choices: Expansionary fiscal policy is used to combat a
recession (see examples
illustrated in Figure 14.1).
1.
Expansionary Policy needed: In Figure 14.1,
a decline in investment has decreased AD from AD1 to AD2
so real GDP has fallen and also employment declined.
Possible fiscal policy solutions follow:
a. An increase in government spending (shifts AD back to the
right).
b. A decrease in taxes (raises income and consumption; AD
shifts right).
c.
A combination of increased spending and
reduced taxes.
d.
If the budget was initially balanced,
expansionary fiscal policy creates a budget deficit.
2.
Contractionary fiscal policy needed: When demand‑pull inflation
occurs as illustrated by a shift from AD3 to AD4 in
the vertical range of aggregate supply in Figure 14.2.
Then contractionary policy is the remedy:
a. A
decrease government spending shifts AD4 back
to AD3.
Here price level returns to its preinflationary level P1.
b. An increase in taxes will reduce income and consumption
and shift back to AD3.
c. A combined spending decrease and tax increase could have
the same effect with the right combination.
III.
Built-In Stabilizers
A.
Built‑in stability arises because net taxes (taxes minus transfers
and subsidies) change with GDP (recall that taxes reduce incomes and
therefore, spending). It
is desirable for spending to rise when the economy is slumping and
vice versa when the economy is becoming inflationary.
Figure 14.3 illustrates how the built-in stability system
behaves.
1.
Taxes automatically rise with GDP because incomes rise and
tax revenues fall when GDP falls.
2.
Transfers and subsidies rise when GDP falls; when these
government payments (welfare, unemployment, etc.) rise, net tax
revenues fall along with GDP.
B.
The strength of automatic stabilizers depends on
responsiveness of changes in taxes to changes in GDP:
The more progressive the tax system, the greater the
economy’s built‑in stability.
In Figure 14.3 line T is steepest with a progressive tax
system.
C.
Automatic stabilizers reduce instability,
but do not eliminate economic instability.
IV.
Evaluating Fiscal Policy
A.
A balanced standardized (full employment)
budget in Year 1 is illustrated in Figure 14.4 because budget
revenues equal expenditures when full-employment exists at GDP1.
B.
At GDP2 there is unemployment and
assume no discretionary government action, so lines G and T remain
as shown.
1.
Because of built‑in stability, the actual
budget deficit will rise with decline of GDP; therefore, actual
budget varies with GDP.
2.
The government is not engaging in
expansionary policy since the budget is balanced at the full
employment level of output.
3.
The standardized budget measures what the
Federal budget deficit or surplus would be with existing taxes and
government spending if the economy is at full employment.
4.
Actual budget deficit or surplus may differ
greatly from full‑employment budget deficit or surplus estimates.
C. Budget
deficits may be either standardized or cyclical.
1.
Standardized deficits occur when there is a
deficit in the full‑employment budget as well as the actual budget.
a.
Standardized deficits signal an expansionary
fiscal policy.
b.
Standardized surpluses indicate
contractionary fiscal policy.
2.
Cyclical deficits refer to when the
standardized budget is balanced, but the actual budget is in deficit
due to a recession.
D.
Global Snapshot 14.1
compares standardized budget deficits for selected countries.
E.
Applying the Analysis:
Recent U.S.
Fiscal Policy
1. Table
14.1 shows the
U.S.
budget experience from 1990 to 2004.
2. Actual
and standardized deficits persisted through most of the 1990s.
3. Personal
and corporate tax rate increases in 1993 reduced the standardized
deficits.
4. The
actual budget moved into surplus in 1998; the standardized in 1999.
5.
Projected surpluses encouraged major tax rate reduction enacted in
2001.
a. Tax rate
cuts helped soften the blow of the 2001 recession.
b. Tax cuts
also turned the standardized surplus back into deficit in 2002.
6. Further
tax cuts and increased spending have increased the deficit but
provided stimulus.
7. Figure
14.5 shows actual and projected surpluses from 1992 to 2012.
V.
Problems, Criticisms and Complications
A.
Problems of timing
1.
Recognition lag is the elapsed time between the beginning of
recession or inflation and awareness of this occurrence.
2.
Administrative lag refers to the time taken to change policy
once the problem has been recognized.
3.
Operational lag is the time elapsed between change in policy
and its impact on the economy.
B.
Political considerations:
Government has other goals besides economic stability, and
these may conflict with stabilization policy.
1.
A political business cycle may destabilize
the economy: Election
years have been characterized by more expansionary policies
regardless of economic conditions, as politicians attempt to
maximize votes rather than pursue macroeconomic stability.
2.
If households expect a policy reversal,
fiscal policy may be ineffective.
Households given a tax cut to encourage consumption, if they
expect the cut to be rescinded, will save the extra disposable
income instead of using it to stimulate total spending.
3.
State and local finance policies may offset federal
stabilization policies.
They are often procyclical, because balanced-budget requirements
cause states and local governments to raise taxes in a recession or
cut spending making the recession possibly worse.
In an inflationary period, they may increase spending or cut
taxes as their budgets head for surplus.
4. The
crowding‑out effect may be caused by fiscal policy.
a. “Crowding‑out” may occur with government deficit
spending. It may increase the interest rate and reduce private
spending which weakens or cancels the stimulus of fiscal policy.
b. Some economists argue that little crowding out will occur
during a recession.
c. Economists agree that government deficits should not
occur at full employment.
C. Current
thinking on fiscal policy
1. Some economists argue that the economy is self-correcting
and fiscal policy is
unnecessary.
However,
2. Most economists believe that fiscal policy is an
important policy tool for pushing the
economy in a particular direction, but not for “fine tuning”
it. Monetary policy is
generally preferred for month-to-month adjustments.
3. In addition to its effects on AD, the productivity (AS)
effects of a fiscal policy need to
be considered.
The effect of fiscal policy is not simply a matter of how many
dollars are
spent (or collected in tax revenue), but also how they are
spent (or from whom they are
collected).
a.
Lower taxes could increase saving and
investment.
b. Lower
personal taxes may increase effort, productivity and, therefore,
shift aggregate
supply to the right.
c.
Lower personal taxes may also increase risk‑taking and,
therefore, shift supply to
the right.
VI.
The Public DebtA.
The public debt is the total amount of money owed by the
Federal government to owners of government securities; equal to the
sum of past budget deficits less surpluses.
B.
The public debt in 2004 was $7.4 trillion.
This is a large number.
One million seconds ago was 12 days back.
One trillion seconds ago was around 30,000 B.C.
C.
Causes of the expansion in debt:
1.
National defense and military spending have soared,
especially during wartime.
During World Wars I and II, debt grew rapidly.
2.
Recessions cause a decline in revenues and growth in
government spending on programs for income maintenance.
Such periods included 1974-75, 1980-82, 1990-91, and 2001.
3.
Tax cuts are another cause.
Tax cuts in the 1980s without equivalent spending cuts led to
increasing debt. The
Clinton
administration in 1993 is an example of how politically difficult it
is to reduce spending and raise taxes to reduce the deficit.
An unpopular deficit reduction act was passed in that year
and many Democrats lost elections later.
D. Ownership of
the debt (Figure 14.6)
1. Public debt is held in the form of
U.S.
securities: Treasury bills, Treasury notes,
Treasury bonds, and U.S. savings
bonds.
2. Ownership of the debt is an important question in terms
of who the Federal government
is obligated to repay, and has implications for whether
U.S.
assets remain in the country.
3. The public held 58 percent in 2004; the Federal
government 42 percent.
4. Foreign interests hold 26 percent of the U.S. public
debt, meaning most of the public
debt is held (and owed) internally.
E. Debt and
GDP
1.
Comparing the debt to GDP is more meaningful than the
absolute level of debt by itself.
Use the example of a family or corporate borrowing.
For a prosperous family or firm, $100,000 worth of debt may
be a small fraction of their income; for others, $100,000 worth of
debt may mean they’re unable to make payments on the debt.
The amount is not as important as the amount relative to the
ability to pay. Also,
most borrowing is made to purchase physical assets such as
buildings, equipment, etc.
Another way to judge government debt is to compare it to an
estimate of public assets.
2.
Figure 14.7 reveals that as a percentage of GDP, Federal debt
held by the public is increasing, but lower than it was in the
1990s.
3.
International comparisons show that other nations have
relative public debts as great or greater than that of the
U.S.
when compared to their GDPs.
See Global Snapshot 14.2.
4.
Interest charges as a percentage of GDP (1.4 percent in 2004)
represent the primary burden of the debt today.
F.
False concerns about the public debt include several popular
misconceptions:
1.
Can the federal government go bankrupt?
There are reasons why it cannot.
a.
The government does not need to raise taxes to pay back the
debt, and it can borrow more (i.e. sell new bonds) to refinance
bonds when they mature.
Corporations use similar methods—they almost always have outstanding
debt.
b.
The government has the power to tax, which businesses and
individuals do not have when they are in debt.
2.
Does the debt impose a burden on future generations?
In 2004 the per capita public debt in the U.S. was $25,200.
But the public debt is a public credit—your grandmother may
own the bonds on which taxpayers are paying interest.
Some day you may inherit those bonds that are assets to those
who have them. The true
burden is borne by those who pay taxes or loan government money
today to finance government spending.
If the spending is for productive purposes, it will enhance
future earning power and the size of the debt relative to future GDP
and population could actually decline.
Borrowing allows growth to occur when it is invested in
productive capital.
G.
Substantive issues do exist.
1.
Repayment of the debt affects income distribution.
If working taxpayers will be paying interest to the mainly
wealthier groups who hold the bonds, this probably increases income
inequality.
2.
Since interest must be paid out of government revenues, a
large debt and high interest can increase tax burden and may
decrease incentives to work, save, and invest for taxpayers.
3.
A higher proportion of the debt is owed to foreigners (about
26 percent) than in the past, and this can increase the burden since
payments leave the country.
But Americans also own foreign bonds and this offsets the
concern.
4.
Some economists believe that public borrowing crowds out
private investment, but the extent of this effect is not clear (see
Figure 14.8).
5.
There are some positive aspects of borrowing even with
crowding out.
a.
If borrowing is for public investment that causes the economy
to grow more in the future, the burden on future generations will be
less than if the government had not borrowed for this purpose.
b.
Public investment makes private investment more attractive.
For example, new federal buildings generate private business;
good highways help private shipping, etc.
|